Transfering public goods to bondholders in zombie banks

Slí Eile06/12/2009

Slí Eile: As the pressure mounts on all sides – media, politics, radio phone-in shows – to cut public spending a question arises about the relationship between what is about to happen, on the one hand, and the on-going bailout of banks, on the other. Orthodox commentary pronounces that there is no relationship between two.Following earlier comments by Colm McCarthy Pat McArdle in the Irish Times (26 November) - ‘No silver bullet rescue from fiscal predicament’ – argues that fiscal adjustment has nothing to do with the banking bailout. Call this the Nil hypothesis.

Lets have another look at the Department of Finance Pre-budget Outlook (PBO) and see if any clues are possible.

The core of the Nil Hypothesis is the following two assertions:
The fiscal deficit – defined as the General Government Balance - must be reduced to a level of 3% by an agreed date with the European Union (that being 2014 in the latest round of concessions to Member States that have exceeded their Stability and Growth Pact guidelines).

The recapitalisation of the banks by the Government has nothing to do with fiscal adjustment since any public liabilities or payments in the current period are ‘off balance sheet’ as far as the measure of General Government Balance is concerned.

There is a lot of deft accountancy footwork going on. The Pre-Budget Outlook Table 6 (Technical Budgetary Projections 2009-2010) throws up some interesting but hard-to-explain shifts in spending composition. The estimated or projected General Government Balance appears in the final row of this table and indicates that the GGB says at a level of -12% of GDP. It reads in the text below:

The current Government working forecast, on the basis of a €4 billion adjustment being delivered in the Budget in December, is for an Exchequer Borrowing Requirement of around €19½ billion in 2010 and a General Government Balance of -12 per cent of GDP.

So, a huge adjustment of €4bn (whatever its composition between tax and spending changes) gives no change in the projected GGB – the measure that exercises Government, EU, ‘the markets’ and most journalists.

A lot of pain for a little in return.

The documentation states that the GGB would be -14% ‘without corrective action’. So, Government proposes to take €4bn out of the economy in the first instance (without calculating the negative multiplier effects of this which are addressed elsewhere by notes-on-the-front drawing on ESRI model data) to yield a saving of 2% points of GDP in the GGB.

But, would such a level of adjustment be required if other parts of the budgetary arithmetic were different? McArdle’s key argument is:

‘If the exchequer were to inject another €4 billion capital into Anglo Irish Bank in the morning, this would increase the EBR (Exchequer Borrowing Requirement) by an equivalent amount but would have no impact whatsoever on the GGD (General Government Deficit).’

The reason given by McArdle is:

‘This is because the international rules treat such capitalisation as a “below the line” transaction, ie investment in a commercial State body which is outside the government sector, rather than current expenditure which affects the deficit.’

This is not a convincing line of argument. Surely, the point about not including contributions to the National Pension Reserve Fund(or any other fund from which taxpayers money is ultimately destined for bank recapitalisation) in the GGB measure is not because it will be cycled through some technically private vehicle (a dubious concept and practice, at best) but because the taxpayer is purchasing assets or share-holding (e.g. preferential share-holding) in banks – be they public, private, zombie or other. The theory is that such payments from the exchequer constitute purchases of assets with long-term value and pay-back and should not, thereby count in the GGB. This conforms to international statistical accounting (Eurostat). So far so good. McArdle is right – technically. Payments to the banks via NPFR or other mechanisms are ‘off balance sheet’ and don’t count towards GGB.

However, GGB is not the only criterion of public solvency – nor indeed are all public liabilities necessarily counted in the components of GGB. An example illustrates the point:

In 2009 Government paid €3bn into the NPRF (instead of the normal €1.5bn per annum). This shows up under the Capital Budget in Table 6 of the PBO. The 2010 entry is zero. Why? Presumably (and I am not aware of any public statement to contradict this) the (extraordinary) upfront payment into the NPRF was to replace funds used to recapitalise the banks. If the State’s holding in these banks proves profitable and effective in generating lending, growth and jobs – in the long-run – then this is arguably a good and necessary investment. But, what if a large chunk of the recapitalisation is going into a black hole known as a zombie bank that has no chance of reclaiming large portions of its debt? In that case, the innocent looking payments into the NPFR in 2009 (which will surely need to be repeated again in 2010 and later years if the banks continue to be short of capital) assume a different meaning. Put another way, ‘there is no free lunch’ – there is an economic opportunity cost beside every payment and transaction. €3bn spent this year instead of €1.5bn into the NPRF means that there is €1.5bn less to spend on health or education or social welfare – no matter what the components of EBR or GGB are.

So, McArdle’s ‘Nil hypothesis’ looks most unconvincing and serves to show that the commentariat is too eager to prove a point when it comes to fiscal adjustment. Parking the banking crisis to one side as either ‘being dealt with’ or ‘irrelevant’ to the size of the deficit that matters is not right.

To sum up – there is a lot of non-transparent shifting of funds – embedded into the aggregate pre-budget figures. The scale of it makes the issue of cuts in the public sector pay bill or child benefit cuts pale into relative numerical insignificance. As always, especially during the boom years, eyes were on this year’s figures and next without any consideration of:

* Long-term damage of inflating or deflating the economy at given point in the economic cycle;
* The hidden long-term acquired costs of particular decisions or non-decisions; and
* The inter-connectedness of economic phenomena rendering markets, profit and income flows, tax receipts and spending decisions extremely vulnerable to sudden shocks and unprojected systemic collapses when one card is pulled from the pile.

In other words, we are in the throws of a global crisis of production and consumption based on short-term private greed. Dysfunctional private sector behaviour exacerbated by dysfunctional political institutions and poorly operating regulatory public services are undermining the capacity of national governments and global inter-governmental agencies to restore balance to public, corporate, household and trade balance sheets. The alternatives to this state of affairs will need to be created by future generations. The current generation needs to address the deficit in fairness and hope created by an orthodoxy that worships at the shrine of just one deficit idols.
One thing I will agree with is McArdle’s comment on:

the failure of successive governments to reform our archaic system of budgetary accounting.

Posted in: EconomicsEconomicsThe Budget

Tagged with: deficitDeflationpre-budget outlook


Share:



Comments

Newsletter Sign Up  

Categories

Contributors

Paul Sweeney

Paul Sweeney is former Chief Economist of the Irish Congress of Trade Unions. He was a …

Vic Duggan

Vic Duggan is an independent consultant, economist and public policy specialist catering …

Robert Sweeney

Robert Sweeney is a policy analyst at TASC and focuses on issues surrounding Irish …



Podcasts